The ABI’s
self-created commission to explore alterations of chapter 11 of the Bankruptcy
Code is scheduled to deliver its report next month. To the extent the recent public statements of
its co-chairs are representative, the commission appears to continue to be
adhering to its initial agenda of weakening secured creditor’ rights on the
premise that, as one of them told
the Wall Street Journal, there has been an "'unmistakable’ progression
of secured lenders’ power in bankruptcy.”
As I have
repeatedly written, the word “unmistakable” is about the last one any unbiased
observer would apply to claims that secured creditors have increased their
advantage or unsecured creditors’ recoveries have declined meaningfully in
recent decades.
1) Large
corporate reorganizations in earlier eras often generated recoveries only for
secured creditors. See my writeup of the
Denver & Rio Grande railroad reorganization for instance.
2) Persons
closely tied to the formulation of the current Bankruptcy Code in 1978 published
articles at the time explaining that secured creditors would receive very
strong protection under the new Code. That
was the quid pro quo for subjecting them to comprehensive bankruptcy laws for
the first time in the nation's history.
3) Claims of some kind of adverse
change in the relative outcomes of secured and unsecured creditors are premised
on a woefully mistaken analysis prepared by a law student with no experience of
any sort, which has been brandied about without critical examination solely only
because it serves the agendas of a number of different constituencies.
Rather, far
from going astray in the past two decades, chapter 11 has actually become modestly
more efficient in fulfilling its public purpose of reorganizing operating
businesses with minimal disruption of the debtor’s operations and the
constituencies who flesh out those operations.
Part of this is due to the natural development of case law resolving
statutory ambiguities and conflicts, fleshing out statutory standards or
filling in statutory gaps, but a large part of it is due to the increased
activity of distressed debt investors, which has led to more accurate and
reliable valuations informed by secondary market liquidity and pricing, and that
in turn has expedited plan negotiations and the resolution of the legal
case. In addition, the impact of
bankruptcy on smaller creditors has been greatly lessened due to the widespread
use of first-day orders and other efficiencies.
Although there are one or two substantive aspects of chapter 11 that I
think could use a dose of reform, in general, I think the process of chapter 11
works far better today than it did during its first decade. Much more debt is being restructured either per
day in bankruptcy or dollar of professional expenses than in restructuring’s
early years. That's increased
efficiency. Thus, I see no genuine case
for reform, although there may be political or economic agendas that lead to
calls for it. It's the classic question
of public interest versus an industry's interest: the public at large gains from a more efficient
resolution process, whereas various constituencies would benefit from making
the process more inefficient or expensive, and getting secured creditors to
absorb the increased cost.
In contrast, I
think the most helpful thing the commission could accomplish would be to
increase the Code’s efficiency and make
it a more efficient mechanism for sucking excess debt out of the real
economy. This would entail just two
steps: first, to codify the best practices and ideas that have been developed
in regard to those determinations that are most frequently litigated, thereby
cutting down on uncertainty and variability and making cases more predictable
and efficient; second, drawing upon the
commission members’ real-world experience to cut through the myths and
incantatory rhetoric that shroud certain formalistic, inefficient and wasteful
practices in chapter 11 to, again, make it more efficient.
But before one
even gets to the Bankruptcy Code, there is one reform of a different law that
would make a huge difference in bankruptcy dockets, and that is, in the fashion
of recent practice in sovereign debt issuance, to revise the Trust Indenture
Act of 1939 to eliminate the need for 100% consent to compromise principal and
interest payments in favor of a lower, but still quite high, super-majority
threshold.
Now, turning to
the Code itself, there are several obvious areas where the efficiency of reorganizations
could be increased nationwide by codifying what are now a patchwork of
individual districts' practices.
1. Codify
First–Day Practice
This is an
obvious and, I expect, uncontroversial reform.
There are well-established procedures, forms and parameters for
“first-day” and “second-day” orders that have been developed in Delaware and
SDNY to pay numerous types of pre-petition claims generated in the ordinary
course of business, and to insulate employees and other non-financial
constituencies from the potential ill effects of a bankruptcy. These are beneficial to society as a whole
because they reduce the scope of disruption from a filing and also enhance
going-concern prospects. Obviously, any
reform should ensure they remain subject to the consent of those who are called
upon to foot the bill, i.e., the
holders of cash collateral and the representatives of unsecured creditors. Enacting these practices into law will also
enhance the administration of chapter 11 cases in venues outside of Delaware
and New York, where occasionally less experienced judges get bogged down by
formalistic doubts about the statutory authority for these eminently sensible
motions and applications. It should be
made unmistakably clear that pre-petition debts, secured or unsecured, can be
paid post-petition in accordance with their terms, or consistent with the
ordinary course of business pre-petition, without the need for motion practice
or court approval, if the debtors’ business judgment is to do so, but subject
to the consent of anyone whose cash collateral is being used to do so, and the
unsecured creditors’ committee.
2. Codify Section 363 Practice
Section 363
sales are, economically, a perfectly sound way to resolve a distressed
situation, when they transfer the operating business to a new entity and leave
the legalistic, litigious bankruptcy
process to deal only with disputes over the proceeds. Formalistic objections that are sometimes
raised (“it’s not a plan’; “there’s no disclosure statement”; “it’s just
helping the secured creditors”) are just that: formalistic, non-economic, non-substantive,
matters of taste. There is nothing
morally or inherently wrong with a resolution called a “sale” as opposed to a
“plan”. Disclosure is a red herring in
the plan process anyway (see point 4 below) and thrusting disclosure statements
and voting into a sale process would make for useless inefficiencies. A case that removes the risk of insolvency
from an operating business efficiently is a net positive for the economy at
large, even if that produces no recovery for unsecureds, if that’s what the
economics lead to. Value is what matters for recoveries, and concerns for
“fairness,” whatever that means in the context of battles among different pools
of capital, can be addressed by making sure junior constituencies get a fair
chance to bid if they are at risk of being squeezed out. But this efficient
method of resolution of financial difficulties should be cemented into the Code
so that it can be implemented consistently and without confusion, in all
districts. Issues like the ability of first lien lenders to credit bid post-Fisker, or the parameters of bidding
protections, or whether a distressed company has to open its books to a
competitor who may not be acting in good faith, should be codified so that the
process becomes completely predictable in all districts.
If optically
helpful, a new chapter could be created to contain the rules for sales of all
or substantially all of the debtor’s operating business. It could provide
timelines that are safe harbors, codify the authority of the buyer to select
which pre-petition liabilities to assume, etc.
3. Codify third-party release terms.
This should be
another non-controversial reform as the content of permissible third-party
release terms is pretty well defined in the major districts and has received
substantial judicial and U.S. Trustee attention. Again, codifying the state of play would make
the best practices nationwide and further the efficient administration of
reorganizations in other districts. As with first-day practice codification,
making third-party releases uniform across the nation will indirectly address
venue concerns, by minimizing uncertainty of plan proponents and constituents.
4. Codify 1129 Practice, but also
Create A Few Clear Rules and
Safe Harbors to Streamline Confirmation Proceedings
Issues like
post-petition interest, the 100% cap on senior classes’ recovery, the need for
competitive bidding on new value plans, deference to market evidence in fixing
cramdown rates, and other like issues have had judicial development since the
Code was enacted and best practices should be codified. Further, clear rules should be enacted
limiting the participation of out-of-the-money constituencies in confirmation
litigation at the estate’s expense. Safe
harbors should be specified such that, if a plan contains them, it is presumed
to satisfy the corresponding confirmation standard, much as the Code now does
for priority tax claims. For example,
broadly accepted valuation methodologies could be safe-harbored, certain
debt-service ratios could be presumed feasible.
More
ambitiously, as opposed to the current treatment of out-of-the-money classes, which
now have to be solicited if they are offered anything, and so are often given
nothing and deemed to reject, a safe harbor could be created that deems the
first out-of-the-money class to accept if they receive a standardized upside
participation in the reorganized debtor, like warrants for X% of its equity
with a strike price that implies full recovery for the senior classes). Also consideration should be given to
establishing a clear rule on debt at emergence to mitigate the risk of chapter
22 -- say, for example a plan is
presumed not feasible if it provides for debt > 4X last 12 months
EBITDA.
5. Codify Clear Criteria for
Substantive Consolidation Under Plans.
Deemed
substantive consolidation is a reasonable approach to classifying claims and
defining distributions in large complex chapter 11 cases where multiple debtors
are liable to the vast majority of creditors. It usually reflects the reality
of how creditors have interacted with and evaluated the creditworthiness of the
debtors as a whole. But there really is no substantive basis for it – nothing
in the Code speaks to it in any explicit way, and the judicial criteria for
true substantive consolidation are extremely expensive to investigate and
litigate. So a very efficient reform
would be to write a clear, simple rule for when it is permissible (or required)
for a plan to effectuate a consolidation just for purposes of the plan: just by
way of illustration, such a rule might be that, when more than 75% of the
assets of the debtors are held by debtors who are jointly and severally liable
for more than 75% of the group’s funded debt, those debtors can be deemed to be
one consolidated debtor for purposes of the plan.
Those are the
codification suggestions. Now, more
controversially, here are three suggested reforms that fall under the heading: "Scrape
Away the Pieties and Dogmas and Look Reality in the Eye":
6. Stop Pretending that the Disclosure
Statement Matters.
Whatever the
vision that informed the Bankruptcy Code at inception, in practice the
disclosure and voting process in chapter 11 cases is a sideshow and a
formality. Far from being a failure, this
is actually a testament to the effectiveness of other mechanisms for creditor
involvement earlier in the process, such as official creditors' committees and
cash collateral budgeting. By the time a
disclosure statement is filed, the major constituencies have seen the data and
analyzed it, their deals are done and the outcome is not the least bit in
doubt. So the truth is, what is in the disclosure statement or not has no
effect on the reorganization. The real decision-making
and the concomitant disclosure happen well before the disclosure statement
hearing, in emails among financial advisors, and in conference rooms and
conference calls where presentations are made and analyzed by the key
constituents and their advisors. The
disclosure statement is in fact, whatever legal weight may be assigned to it, merely
a record for posterity of what the debtor and the supporters of its plan have
come to a consensus on. I doubt that
anybody reads the disclosure statement except the professionals who create
it. I don’t think I have ever known a
judge to read the whole thing. Many of
the sections are merely recitations of past events that are otherwise
memorialized in one public repository or another. The hearing on its adequacy is at best a
status conference for the judge to learn who is not on board and what the
issues at confirmation are going to be. So
let the judge hold whatever status conference s/he wants to, but cut the
document that goes to creditors down to just a short plan summary, term sheet
proxies for its exhibits, the financial projections and the going concern
valuation. That is all that anybody
really reads and it will get rid of the silly process of people filing
objections that are speaking briefs for confirmation.
7. Recognize that Management is Biased
– But Its Bias Is Consistent with Public Policy
The Code, and
many pro-debtor judges, treat debtors in possession as if they were neutral
fiduciaries. But it’s an open secret
that management has an incentive to come out of bankruptcy with the most
conservative capital structure possible.
It makes their job easier and also makes any equity package they
negotiate for themselves more valuable. This benefits senior creditors, to be
sure, at the expense of potential upside for junior creditors. Everyone in the process knows this.
Two corollaries
flow from it in regard to reform: 1) this is not necessarily a bad thing,
because there is a public interest in seeing companies emerge with conservative
balance sheets as opposed to having chapter 22’s due to insufficient
de-leveraging in the first reorganization.
A conservative capital structure actually furthers that policy, as long
as it is in good faith, even though some constituencies suffer.
But the key is,
are these plans and projections in good faith or is the debtor sandbagging
revenue and expense reduction opportunities until post-emergence? Is there a consolidation that might generate
higher value?
So, 2) let’s
recognize this bias exists, and stop giving non-disinterested debtors such a
controlling role in plan promulgation.
Create a mechanism that, in an orderly fashion, previews recoveries to
the court at an early stage and, if it appears that some significant
constituency is going to be left out of the money, empowers the court to obtain
an independent expert review of the projections, strategies and assumptions
well prior to confirmation, and then -- if he or she is not satisfied with the
conclusions of the review -- to authorize the pursuit of alternatives. Some activist judges do this already but it
should be formalized to supply best practices, rather than ad hoc. Courts should encourage out-of-the-money
constituencies to supply ideas and alternative perspectives to whomever the
court appoints to perform the independent review.
8. Conform the Law to the Reality of
Real Estate Chapter 11’s
Most real
estate chapter 11 cases are just changes in ownership, with no impact on unaffiliated
constituencies such as employees or trade creditors, and there is no benefit
from any kind of a plan process. Often, the plan process just delays and makes
more expensive the inevitable outcome of the first lien taking the property
back. This reality should be faced up to
and all real estate cases, save those with some appreciable proportion of trade
debt, should be shuttled into orderly 363 sales to the highest bidder with the
mortgagees being able to credit bid. Not
just single-asset real estate. All real
estate businesses – hotels, apartments, office complexes, malls, etc. If they don’t have a sufficiently large
component of operating creditors, run them as orderly sales. This prospect will certainly reduce the
number of bad faith, eve-of-foreclosure filings, gerrymandered voting plans,
and absurd “Till in chapter 11” litigation.
The next three provisions
can be loosely grouped under the theme of "cutting back on expense and
bullshit".
9. Let Judges Bring Common Sense to
Examiner Provisions
This is another
reform that should be noncontroversial. Often the examiner motion is made for
ulterior motives related to the prospective terms of a plan and solely to
delay. Judges should have more
discretion to squelch examiner motions late in the game. On the other hand, judges often use “examiners’
as “deputy bankruptcy judges” or mediators and thought should be given as to
whether this is a sound practice. It’s certainly an expensive one. Last, perhaps more controversial because it
would limit professional fee opportunities, examiner investigations are often
duplicative of work either the unsecureds can do or have done (such as
fraudulent transfer analysis), or the Justice Department or other governmental
actor or the plaintiffs’ bar is contemporaneously doing, and the Code should
inhibit such duplicative tasks. The
examiner’s report in the Lehman bankruptcy is an extreme example of this
problem, in that the examiner, one presumes in all good faith, ran up a bill of
over $50 million to investigate matters that were separately investigated by
multiple other private and public sector actors and generated a report of
absolutely no consequence to the reorganization at all. That should not be allowed to happen again.
10. Eliminate 544(b) in Favor of a Uniform
Federal Substantive and Procedural Standard, Which
Should Be Modified to Eliminate Financial Speculation on Costly Litigation
One of the
biggest fee-generators in a large chapter 11 is the pursuit of constructive
fraudulent transfers. Of course,
“constructive fraudulent transfer cases” have nothing to do with “fraud” – that
is separately covered by laws voiding intentional fraudulent transfers. Rather, they are just attacks -- incredibly
expensive hindsight attacks -- on valuation or on affiliate guarantees or other
structural or documentary matters that are staples of sound credit policy. A case like the TOUSA fraudulent transfer
litigation, for instance – it cost millions of dollars and many hundreds of
hours of judicial branch resources and what real-world good did it accomplish?
It just moved money around from one group of lenders to the enterprise to another
group of lenders. It was really just a
giant, bloated preference action in effect, if not in name. What federal policy would encourage
investing tens of millions of dollars and hundreds of hours of judicial
resources for nothing more than moving the recovery around between different
sets of financial institutions, as opposed to the much less expensive option of
living with the structure as it lay when the bankruptcy filing occurred? None that I can see, although it did generate
good income for the professionals involved.
Because of
544(b)’s incorporation of state law (without specification of a clear rule for
ascertaining which state), those attacks frequently produce excessively
complicated, fee-generating issues of choice of law, deliberations over
differing statute of limitations, and debates over whether 544(b)’s requirement
of an unsecured creditor with a valid avoidance action exists or not. Those disputes are not consistent with the
Constitution’s concept of a “uniform”
law on bankruptcy or with the need for economy in administering a bankruptcy
case. No cognizable federal purpose is
served by these collateral procedural disputes.
They simply delay the resolution of the merits and increase the cost of
getting to that point. They should be
eliminated by striking 544(b) and focusing instead on the federal counterpart,
currently found in 548(a).
But even the
federal substantive law needs refreshing.
First and foremost, the alternative remedy of avoidance of the transfer
– which transfer often occurred several years before the judgment might be
entered and may have involved a large diverse quantity of assets and people –
is outdated, impractical, and needs to be eliminated in favor of a simple
damages award.
Secondly, to
eliminate unproductive and inequitable speculation in lawsuits of this type, that
simple damages award should be set by a fixed
formula: the amount owed at the time of the chapter 11 filing to creditors on those
claims that existed at the time of the transfer, and who did not finance the
harmful transfer, plus interest and the plaintiff's costs of litigation. That wlill make them whole, no more, no less.
Further, the payments should be made directly to the damaged creditors or their
assignees, so that their recoveries are not diluted by other claimants of the
estate that suffered no harm and may have financed the transaction in the first
place.
By "inequitable",
I mean the Moore v Bay paradigm whereby the existence of one unsecured claim
with an avoidance action, no matter how small, enables the estate to seek to go
after the entire transfer, even amounts well in excess of that needed to make
the injured creditor whole, whereupon investors who are strangers to the case
go out and acquire other claims against the estate, which may have had no
injury from the transfer and may in fact have financed it to profit from the
lawsuit). On top of that, you sometimes get cases, like Mirant, where a plan
provides a 100% payout to unsecured creditors and yet fraudulent transfers are
still pursued because the Code has been formalistically construed to require
only benefit to “the estate”.
In other
words, repeal Moore v Bay and have prosecution of avoidance actions be a
creditors' remedy, not the estate's. These
simple changes would end the unproductive and inequitable exploitation of antiquated
legal rules for financial speculation.
11. Pay Professionals out of their
Constituencies’ Recoveries.
Some of the
Commission’s hearings have had to do with ways to control expenses in
bankruptcy. Right now, unsecureds and equity committees consistently get paid
out of cash collateral of senior secured creditors, and, in turn senior secured
and DIP creditors get their professionals paid on top of principal and
interest, which fees ultimately reduce unsecured recoveries. The combined effect is that no constituency
has the combined ability and incentive to limit any professionals' activities, and thus expenses are essentially
uncontrolled. I think the best solution
that has been suggested, and even on
rare occasions already implemented, is that, while all constituencies should
have the right to appear and be heard through professionals, they should also
have bear their own professional costs out of their own plan recoveries. Internalizing professional expenses will give
every constituency an incentive to present only plausible arguments and
theories and refrain from fishing expedition discovery, and in turn that will
serve to streamline the proceedings considerably.
This last idea
can simply be filed under "The
Impossible Dream "
12. Treat Every Single Legacy Employment
Claim as General Unsecured.
Finally, a
reform that I think would be appropriate given the patchwork nature of the Code
and of the circuits’ interpretation of
it would be to treat all legacy employment claims as pre-petition general
unsecured claims. By legacy, I mean pension,
retiree medical, WARN, general employee litigation, indemnification of officers
and directors for pre-petition litigation, and the like. . Right now, retiree
medical claims are privileged as to priority for no sound policy reason given
the existence of multiple Federal and State health insurance programs like
Medicare, Medicaid, Obamacare, and so on; pension modification usually requires
a separate non-bankruptcy litigation with the PBGC; the priority WARN claims
receive varies based on facts and circumstances that may be litigated;
indemnification claims are often upgraded under the plan because they can be,
and no one wants to alienate the management.
All of them should be seen as what they are, relative to the purpose of
chapter 11 to reorganize the business in the way that makes it the strongest
contributor to the economic future of the nation and the local communities:
they are legacy liabilities that should be separated from the going concern,
not burden it going forward. But
politically, I would doubt very much that anything that put retirees behind
reorganization would have much chance of success, so I left if off the list as
a concession to that political reality.
.
No comments:
Post a Comment