Judge Drain's recent bench ruling in the Momentive Performance confirmation
hearing rests primarily on the
proposition that profit has "no place" in calculating the interest rate payable to
secured creditors under a plan satisfies the standards of section
1129(b)(2)(A)(i). His ruling invokes two chapter 13 cases, In re Valenti in the 2d Circuit and the
plurality opinion in Till v SCS Credit
Corp., and treats them as binding in chapter 11 as well. I have written at length about the reason why
the second part of that reasoning is wrong, that Till was entirely chapter 13-specific. Now I want to write about the first part, the
substantive claim that profit has "no place" in valuing cramdown paper. As I did in my deep dive into Till, I have gone back to the opinions
the Supreme Court issued in the 1940s affirming the absolute priority rule in
chapter X and railroad reorganization cases, on the twin premises that (1) they
embody the law as it existed when chapter 11 was drafted to replace them, and (2)
the absence of any legislative evidence that Congress meant to overrule those
cases when it enacted chapter 11 means those cases are still good law for
chapter 11 purposes. Neither Till nor Valenti cite any legislative history in support of their reasoning
that profit has "no place" in cramdown paper valuation, just lower
court cases.
As younger readers may not be aware, let me first
note that the Bankruptcy Reform Act made some changes to the role of the fair
and equitable standard and the absolute priority rule in confirming plans of
reorganization, but those were largely procedural. The principal change was to empower classes protected by the standard/rule to
override it by acceptance of the plan, meaning that the
standard/rule only came into play for a non-accepting class; the effect of this
was to eliminate the ability of dissenters within the accepting class to invoke the
standard/rule -- they were remitted only to the protection of the best interests
standard. Secondarily, the role of the
SEC (or, in the case of railroad reorganizations, the ICC) to pass muster on
the substantive economics of the plan, among other things, was eliminated in
favor of allowing the parties in interest to bargain toward a consensus against
the backdrop of the applicability of the standard/rule.
But those were procedural changes. I think it is quite evident that the
substantive standard/rule was not weakened in the slightest from the "full
compensation" mandate in cases like Consolidated
Rock Products and the cases I will review in this post. Indeed, in his
contemporaneous explanation of the then-new cramdown matrix, Ken Klee, the
"author of the Bankruptcy Code" (because he was the staff member of
the House Judiciary Committee that took the lead in writing the Bankruptcy
Reform Act of 1978) stated that the new Code would afford additional "protection
for secured claims that is not provided under present law. " See
"All You Ever Wanted to Know About Cramdown Under the New Bankruptcy
Code"53 American Bankruptcy Law Journal 133, 143 (1979). Elsewhere in the article (page 158), Klee wrote, "The discount rate [used in computing the present value of a stream of deferred cash payments on a secured claim] is equivalent to the rate of interest that would be paid on an obligation of the debtor considering a market rate of interest that reflects the risk of the debtor's business." (Emphasis added). In a companion article, Ron Trost, a member
of the National Bankruptcy Conference that was deeply involved in the 1970s reform project,
wrote: "In the usual chapter 11 case either secured creditors will consent
to the plan or the business will not be able to be reorganized." Trost, Business Reorganizations Under Chapter
11 of the New Bankruptcy Code" 34 Business Lawyer 1309, 1335 n. 182 (1979)
(Parenthetical observation: keep that in
mind when you hear someone argue that the Code as enacted in 1978 struck a
purported balance between debtor and creditor that has somehow shifted over
time in favor of the secured creditor; that's just not true).
The Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978's changes to prior law reflected a broader trend in the legislation of that decade toward deregulation, which was seen in the airline deregulation legislation and changes President Carter made in the makeup of regulatory agencies; motor carrier (trucking) deregulation; and railroad deregulation, and initial aspects of banking deregulation. All of those laws reduced heavy-handed regulation by New Deal government agencies (the CAB, ICC, etc.) in favor of increased respect for market forces. One of the intellectual drivers of the trend was now-Justice Stephen Breyer, who was then a protege of Senator Ted Kennedy, who sponsored several of the deregulating bills Breyer said at the time:
"Efforts, both here and abroad, to have people guess what the market
would produce if it were free to create a price are so very different in
their result from what the market does produce when it is free that it
becomes a kind of parody of a free market situation."
Quoted in Andrew Crain, "Ford, Carter and Deregulation in the 1970s", 5 Journal on Communication and High-Tech Law 413, 425 (2007). In the case of the era's bankruptcy reform, there were many alternative approaches debated throughout the decade, but it was clearly the consensus outcome that the SEC's role was virtually eliminated, and a more laissez-faire environment arose in which the parties were encouraged to reach privately negotiated resolutions within parameters set by the substantive provisions of section 1129.
It's implausible in my estimation that a law passed in that era dealing with commercial financial situations was intended to eliminate market and profit considerations from judicial analysis, especially given that the reform act was the subject of years of legislative revision, debate and study through three Congresses before it was passed and such a contrarian perspectie does not manifest itself in the legislative history.
In addition to those contemporary insights into the intent behind the Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978, it is very instructive to turn back to
the 1940s, to see not just what the law was, but what section 1129(b)(2)(A) really means today. Perhaps the reader has already read my re-visiting of Consolidated Rock Products from1940. In this post, I will explain how RFC v. Denver & Rio Grande WesternRailroad Co., 328 U.S. 495 (1946) and its companion case Insurance Group Committee v. Denver &Rio Grande Western Railroad Co., 329 U.S. 607 (1947) establish the
following proposition: because a secured
creditor class is entitled to "full compensation" for any alteration
of its rights by a reorganization plan, if it is necessary to achieve full
compensation that the creditor class make a profit, then profit must be
afforded the creditor to satisfy the fair and equitable standard. This proposition of course, negates the
converse, that profit has "no place" in cramdown treatments. Of course, a debtor can always pay off the
creditor in cash at confirmation, or reach a consensual bargain with the
creditor, and obviate analysis of the topic.
But the creditor class cannot be forced to take back paper priced below
par just because a higher rate would enable a profit to occur. (Note, this is slightly different than saying
the paper must actually trade at a market value of 100 per cent. Courts are not infallible and the other
creditors were not legally obligated to insulate the creditor against market
fluctuations. It is clear from the
pre-Code cases that no court was applying the rule that strictly. What they were requiring, though, was a good-faith, well-reasoned
valuation, backed by specific evidence, and not an off-the-rack formula, that led
to the conclusion that, more likely than not, the secured creditor would hold
something worth 100 cents of its claim upon confirmation).
The Facts of the Case
As the two Denver & Rio Grande Railroad cases
are over 70 years old, they use a number of unfamiliar terms and references that
make reading the opinions more laborious than modern opinions. Yet the effort pays off as the underlying plan
issues turn out to bear a close resemblance to those presented by many modern
chapter 11 cases.
The railroad filed its petition for reorganization
in 1935. Its capital structure was
complex, as was typical of the railroad reorganizations of the era, principally
because various branches and subsystems and asset classes had been separately
financed from one another and from the system as a whole. So while various creditors thus had first
liens on parts of the system, there was another layer of secured debt, the
General Mortgage Bonds, that had blanket, but junior, liens on the system as a
whole. There were other layers of
creditors and equity holders, but on the valuation that the ICC and the district
court adopted, there was no value for anyone below the two classes of secured
debt, and the other stakeholders were eliminated under the plan. So this was quite analogous to many cases we see
today: first lien holders and second lien holders battling over the enterprise
value, with everybody else out of the money.
Based on the aforementioned ICC and court approved valuation,
the plan provided that the first liens would get a package of secured debt instruments
and new stock amounting to 90% of the reorganized debtor's equity, while the
second liens would receive only the remaining 10% of the equity.
The Proceedings Below
The plan was proposed on the basis of an effective
date of January 1, 1943. It cleared the
ICC in June of that year, and was confirmed by the district court in June 1944
after creditor voting. The first liens
voted in favor and the second liens (General Mortgage Bonds) voted against the
plan. Several appeals were taken from confirmation,
principally arguing that the valuation and consequently the treatment of
creditors had failed to account for the "excess war profits" the
railroad would reap after the effective date, 90% of which would, per the plan,
flow to the first lien holders through the common stock stake awarded them
under the plan. For present purposes, the
fact that the case turned on the awarding of "profits" to first lien
holders makes the case highly relevant to Till-in-chapter-11
analysis, as exemplified in Momentive
Performance.
The circuit court of appeals agreed with the
appellants, whereupon the secured creditors brought the case to the Supreme
Court. The appellate court had ruled
that the secured creditors were over-compensated by the debtor's plan as approved
by the ICC and the district court: "The
senior bondholders were paid in full.
They received all the new securities and most of the common stock. Ninety percent of the General Mortgage Bonds
were wiped out, . They received only a small amount of the common stock, ten
per cent of their total claim. ... We
think any plan which fails to take this [buildup of huge retained earnings
during WW2] into account and gives the Senior Bondholders their claims in full
by substantially delivering the road to them, and gives them the surplus cash
actually on hand and further enables them
to receive in addition the excess war profits which are reasonably sure to come,
is inherently inequitable and unfair, so long as there are class of creditors
whose claims are not fully satisfied."
(Emphasis added)
The first liens argued to the Court that " The
circuit court defeats the private right of creditors to full satisfaction of
their claims. The senior creditors are
entitled to realizable value in the full amount of their bonds before the
general mortgage bonds are entitled to anything. (Citing the then recent
Supreme Court opinions Case v. Los Angeles Lumber; Consolidated
Rock Products; Ecker v. Western Pacific; and Group of Inst'l Investors. v.
Chicago, Milwaukee & St. Paul Ry Co.)"
The Supreme Court's Opinion
In a 7-1 ruling, the Supreme Court reversed the
circuit, reinstated the confirmation of the plan, and justified the award of
"profits" to the first lien holders as necessary to achieve
"full compensation" under the fair and equitable standard.
The Court said: "junior claims can receive
nothing until the senior claims receive securities of a worth or value equal to
their indebtedness. The [General
Mortgage Bonds] are definitely junior [to the holders of liens on discrete
systems within the overall railroad]. The
Commission did not make a finding that the cash value of the securities awarded
the senior claims as of the effective date of the plan equalled [sic] the face
of the claims. It did, however, carefully state its reasons for concluding that
compensation 'flowing under the plan to the various classes of bondholders for
the rights surrendered by them' was adequate in the light of the full priority
rule. For those classes, other than the
Junior Generals, that received common stock, the Commission said that the
possibility of 'unlimited dividends on common stock' was a factor in offsetting
loss of position. Thus it is clear that when the Commission made its
allocations it had definitely in mind that one thing that gave the senior
creditors compensation for the admission of junior claimants to participation
in securities before the seniors obtained full cash payment was their chance to
share in the unlimited dividends that might be earned and paid on the common
stock to have a part in the 'lush years'." 328 U.S. at 517-18.
In a section of the opinion titled "Cash and
War Earnings", the Court noted that the ICC had justified the plan's departure
from full cash equivalency by the fact that the senior secured bondholders
would receive 90% of the common stock and thereby participate in the
"excess war profits". "The
error of the Circuit Court lies in its assumption that the senior bondholders
were paid in full by the securities allotted to them without also accepting the
determination of the Commission ... as of January 1, 1943, [that] all
subsequent earnings were a part also of the common stock that was awarded the senior bondholders." 328 U.S. at 523-24.
In other words, it was the profit component, conveyed
through the common stock distributed to the first liens, that saved the plan from
failing the fair and equitable test!
"[T]hrough these common stock advantages the [secured creditors]
may be compensated for their loss of payment in full in cash." Id. at 525.
A Second Bite at the First Liens' Apple
After the Court issued its opinion, the railroad
debtor went back to its reorganization court for permission to abandon its
confirmed plan in favor of one that gave better treatment to the junior
constituencies. It argued changed
circumstances, in particular that, due to the "radical lowering of money
rates for the indefinite future", the interest payable to the secured
creditors under the plan as confirmed was just too damn high. Once again, the district court rejected the
attempt, but the circuit court stayed the lower court's order to consummate the
plan. The first liens took the matter
before the Supreme Court again.
In Insurance Group Committee v. Denver & R.G.W.R. Co., 329 US 607 (1947), the Court,
again with only one dissenter, vacated the appellate court's ruling and
reinstated the district court's order.
The Court confirmed its holding from the prior year: "To justify
the change of position of creditors from fully secured to partially secured,
creditors were given opportunities to
participate in profits through common stock ownership with a change at
larger earnings than the Commission's forecast anticipated. We held the priority rule was satisfied by
this type of allocation." 329 U.S. at 617 (emphasis added).
Regarding the allegedly excessive interest rate on
the debt instruments issued to the first liens, the Court said: " As none of the authorized securities is alleged by the debtor
to have shown values much above par, the chosen rates of return have not proven
to be excessive." Id. at 615. Supporting that statement, the Court
footnoted a table taken from Moody's that showed the first lien bonds included
in the package of debt and equity issued to the first liens had traded in the
102.89-103.82 range during 1945 and 46, although they had traded below 90
during 1947, and the package as a whole was not precisely valued by the Court: "The debtor has made no
allegation ... that the existing cash value of the securities allotted any
creditor has ever aggregated the amount of the creditor's claim against the debtor. ... Until it can be contended with
some show of reasonableness that the creditor[senior creditors[ have received
more in value than the face of their claims, the debtor's insistence on a
re-examination of the plan is without substantial support [citing Northern Pacific Railway v Boyd and Group of
Institutional Investors]. ... the
debtor [fails] to allege any actual sales or value of the securities which
would show that the creditor have received through the allotted securities
payments on their claims in excess of their face...."
Clearly the Court found market values relevant, not
as the sole determinant of the "fair and equitable" analysis, but as
a very relevant component thereof. And the Court clearly reaffirmed the crucial
role of profits in satisfying the fair and equitable standard. As these cases has never been questioned in
subsequent Supreme Court opinions, or in the legislative revisions of the
bankruptcy law since then, these principles remain good law in the chapter 11
context.
No comments:
Post a Comment