I’ve devoted most
of my analysis so far into trying
to persuade the reader that the plurality opinion in Till was chapter 13-specific and does not provide substantial
support for the use of the “prime-plus” formula in chapter 11s. In this post, I will focus on the passages in
Till -- other than footnote 14, which
I will go over separately in the next post -- that have been invoked to
application of the “prime plus” formula to cram-ups under section
1129(b)(2)(A). These passages are dicta,
of course, but that is not a bar to the reasoning, just a caution.
Early in Section II of the plurality opinion, the first
section of legal analysis, after conceding the “Bankruptcy Code gives little
guidance”, the four justices observe that the Bankruptcy Code “includes
numerous provisions that, like the cram down provision, require a court to
‘discount a stream of deferred payments back to … present dollar value,’”
(citations omitted). The opinion drops a
footnote here that references, inter alia,
§ 1129(b)(2)(A). Then, the opinion
continues, “We think it likely that Congress intended bankruptcy judges and
trustees to follow essentially the same approach when choosing an appropriate
interest rate under any of these provisions.”
From these words, one could conclude that the plurality was intending the
“prime plus” formula they were about to endorse in 13's should apply as well in
11's.[1]
However, I hear something different in this language. Because it's placed at the very beginning of
the opinion's discussion of the law, it likely is more a preface to a line of
reasoning than the conclusion that follows from that reasoning. I think the plurality was merely trying to
say that it believed the “prime plus”
approach it was about to endorse was “essentially the same approach” as
pre-existing law under chapter 11, not a major departure from it, and any deviation from prior precedent was only a
pragmatic reformulation of the prior law to reflect the administrative
challenges of chapter 13. Hence the
qualifier ,"essentially" which I take to singal "we're doing
something a little different here, not a lot". The Court has said on numerous occasions
(e.g., Dewsnup) that, when
interpreting the Bankruptcy Code, they will presume, absent evidence to the
contrary, that Congress did not intend to depart from well-established practice
under the prior law. I think the
"essentially the same approach" passage is just a different way of
making the same point.
And I think, at a high level of generality (i.e., setting aside for the moment the
"highest feasible present value" passage discussed in the last post),
that is a defensible perspective. While
Congress made one major change to prior practice regarding the “fair and
equitable” standard in the Bankruptcy Code, by enabling the standard to be
bypassed if a class consents to its treatment by the margins established by
section 1126, there is no evidence that Congress intended to change the
substance of the standard when the class dissents and the standard has to be
applied. Thus, since our focus is on the
use of Till in chapter 11, we should
continue to look at the Court's prior precedents
in the business reorganization context to see what Congress intended to
incorporate into the “fair and equitable” test in chapter 11, which the
plurality implies they continue to view as operative.
I don't propose to take up the reader's time by going over
well-plowed ground, since there are many articles that cover the topic broadly
(a brief and clear history of those cases can be found in this article
by Pamela Foohey, a professor of law at the University of Illinois). Instead, I will confine my analysis to a
short, but in-depth look at the last of the Supreme Court’s major pre-Code
opinions on the subject of compensating creditors for the restructuring of
their contract rights, Consolidated Rock Products v. Dubois, which I think is the most
relevant precedent.
Consolidated Rock Products was a holding company, with two
operating subsidiaries, Union and Consumers, each of which had separate debt
issues outstanding. Today we would call
those issues “structurally senior” to the parent’s creditors, although the
parent had no bank or capital market debt, just preferred and common. The subs had substantial net intercompany
claims against the parent. All three
were in a jointly administered reorganization case under § 77(B). The plan
confirmed by the district court awarded the subs’ bondholders a package of new
bonds, preferred and warrants to buy common stock, and allowed the parent’s
stockholders to retain all the common on the reorganized company. It also ignored, and wiped out without
analysis, the intercompany claims, and extinguished as well the unpaid
pre-petition interest on the subs’ bonds without consideration.
The Court granted cert because of “the importance in the
administration of the reorganization provisions of the Act of certain
principles” presented by the case, and reversed, by way of an opinion authored
by Justice Douglas, certainly no friend of the moneyed interests.
First, the Court decided that the intercompany claim was a
claim against the parent and thus was entitled, by dint of the absolute
priority rule, to receive any value of the parent’s estate, for the benefit of
their own creditors, before the parent’s stockholders could retain any equity.
Secondly, or alternatively, the Court said, even if the
intercompany claims were not valid because corporate formalities had not been
respected or assets had been commingled, still the subsidiary’s creditors were
senior to the parent’s stockholders on a consolidated basis, and entitled to
application of the absolute priority rule that equity receives nothing until
the creditors are “made whole”.
Then, the Court articulated additional problems with the
plan. I’ll skip over the first – apportionment of the reorganized company’s
value between the respective subsidiaries’ bondholders, which is not relevant
here – to focus on the second, which is the more well-known and more relevant
portion of the opinion. In that portion,
Justice Douglas faulted the reorganization court for its failure to “value the
whole enterprise by a capitalization of prospective earnings”. Quoting a Holmes opinion from an earlier era,
he wrote: “'the commercial value of property consists in the expectation of
income from it.’” So here we see the Court, in its last pre-Code opinion on the
“fair and equitable” standard, linking “value” in the “fair and equitable”
context with “expectation of income”, which -- contrary to Justice Thomas's
concurrence -- implies a risk-adjusted discount rate, not a risk-free one.
This inference is reinforced by the rest of the paragraph:
Since
its application requires a prediction as to what will occur in the future, an
estimate, as distinguished from mathematical certitude, is all that can be made.
But that estimate must be based on an informed judgment which embraces all
facts relevant to future earning capacity and hence to present worth,
including, of course, the nature and condition of the properties, the past
earnings record, and all circumstances which indicate whether or not that
record is a reliable criterion of future performance. A sum of values based on
physical factors and assigned to separate units of the property without regard
to the earning capacity of the whole enterprise is plainly inadequate.
In the first two sentences, the Court uses the words
“prediction”. “estimate”, and “informed judgment”, all of which entail much
more than a mechanical application of a risk-free rate or a pre-ordained
formula or a highly constrained range of rates to a promised stream of payments;
in particular, in the phrase “all circumstances which indicate whether or not
that record is a reliable criterion of future performance” the reference to
“all circumstances” clearly takes the court out of the realm of anything
mechanical. So too the phrase “whether
or not”, contrasted with the notion of “mathematical certitude,” which is
dismissed as impossible, plainly indicates that there is uncertainty and thus
risk that the court is expected to take into account.[2]
In its next section, Justice Douglas's opinion delivered an
even stronger message that bears directly on the contemporary use of Till in chapter 11 cases. He observed, first, that “The bondholders for
the principal amount of their 6% bonds receive an equal face amount of new 5% income bonds and preferred stock,
while the preferred stockholders receive new common stock” (emphasis
added).
But, the Court held, “the bondholders have not been made whole.
They have received an inferior
grade of securities, inferior in the sense that the interest rate has been
reduced, a contingent return has been substituted for a fixed one, the maturities have been in part extended and in
part eliminated by the substitution of preferred stock, and their former strategic position has been
weakened. Those lost rights are of
value. Full compensatory
provision must be made for the entire bundle
of rights which the creditors surrender.” (Emphasis added again).
This mandate is being overlooked in the application of Till in chapter 11 cases. What the courts using Till to cramdown secured debt have been doing is just what the
Supreme Court said, in Consolidated Rock,
failed the absolute priority test, in
particular extending maturities, and tinkering with interest rates to make
plans feasible. The Court said that those steps make a secured creditor less
than whole and cannot pass muster under the rule; the creditors’ rights “are
not recognized, in cases where stockholders are participating in the plan, if
creditors are given only a face amount of
inferior securities equal to the face amount of their claims”.
For example, when both Justice Thomas and the dissenter in
the Seventh Circuit contended that the risk of default was already priced in to
the loan when made and thus the lender was not entitled to any risk adjustment
in the reorganization, that clearly contradicts Consolidated Rock’s holding.
The maturity of the debt in Till,
as in many of the chapter 11 cases applying it, was extended as part of the
cramdown.
Consolidated Rock teaches that the “fair and equitable” rule
requires that the creditor be “compensated” for the extension. A risk–free rate cannot provide any
compensation for an extension of maturity when the initial contract rate was
above the risk-free rate to begin with. This
1943 article by an analyst at the SEC, which
played a much larger role in reorganizations then, confirms that Consolidated
Rock was contemporaneously so interpreted, to require a risk-adjusted
capitalization rate.
So, too, when the plurality in Till went off on the “highest feasible present value” tangent, they
subordinated the “fair and equitable” standard to the goal of helping debtors
reorganize and thus departed significantly from prior business reorganization precedent.
Whether that is defensible in the 13 context as a pragmatic matter, I
don't propose to dwell on.[3]
It’s also critical to recognize that the Court in Consolidated Rock was talking about more
factors than just an interest rate. They
are talking about maturity, collateral, “strategic position” (which I take to
be a reference to the absolute priority of debt over equity and a blessing by
the Court of the often-discomfiting effect that has on equity owners' wishes) and
the whole package of contract rights “lost” in the restructuring. This essential aspect of the fair and
equitable analysis has been forsaken in the application of Till in chapter 11. Courts
today seem to be acting as if, because Till
dealt just with an interest rate, the only “fair and equitable” inquiry is
"what is the interest rate?" Consolidated Rock makes clear the whole
package of terms has to be analyzed and all impairments of the original bargain
have to be compensated. Nothing in Till addresses the treatment of other
issues, nor does anything in a consumer case like Till suggest that the more complex analysis required by Consolidated Rock
has been thrown out the window.
Justice Douglas ends the paragraph by affirming that the
“fair and equitable” rule emanates not just from dry statutory language, but
equity: “The plan then comes within judicial denunciation because it does not
recognize the creditors' 'equitable
right to be preferred to stockholders against the full value of all
property belonging to the debtor corporation'” (Emphases in this paragraph
added).
[1] One could also conclude that the reference to
bankruptcy courts "choosing an appropriate interest rate" for
cramdown paper provides additional evidence that the justices in the plurality
lacked a strong understanding of the process of plan formulation and confirmation and of the respective
roles of plan proponents, who are the ones who actually "choose" a rate
to propose, and bankruptcy judges, who decide if the proposed treatment of the
affected claim satisfies the statute's standards. Although I think that is fairly plausible, as
none of those justices seem to have any prior experience with reorganization
cases, the interest rate question still needs to be tackled, so the analysis
has to go beyond just saying, "well, they just didn't have a strong grasp
of reorganization practice" and needs to explain what the reorganization
practice is.
[2] In the third and last
sentence, the Court clearly rejects a valuation of merely tabulating static
“property” values, and clearly holds that the fair and equitable analysis is to
be based on a “going concern” valuation.
[3] As I indicated in my fourth post, fn.3, I think there are better reference rates than the prime rate for used car
loans that may actually work to chapter 13 debtors' benefit.
No comments:
Post a Comment