At the end of my post six months ago on the Texas Grand Prairie
opinion from the Fifth Circuit, I indicated that I would follow up with a post
about why I think a challenge to the application of Till v.
SCS Credit Corp., in chapter 11 cases would have merit. Many things intervened, including long
stretches of great weather when I chose not to sit down at a PC, but this is
it. While I initially thought my post would
be a brief review of the Till plurality
opinion followed by a slightly longer explanation of the errors of economic
analysis that bankruptcy courts have been making in their interpretation and
application of the footnote from the plurality opinion that refers to “an
efficient market”, as I delved into the background of the Till opinion, I found several interesting facts that, as far as I
can tell, have never received the attention they deserve and so the initial
idea has expanded to a much longer review that I have broken into several more
digestible segments. Following this post, which summarizes the
facts of the case, its lower court history and the state of the law as the
issue came before the Court, there are:
1) a couple of posts that take a “deep dive”
into the briefs and the extremely revealing oral argument presented to the
Court;
2) an analysis of the plurality opinion, with
particular attention to the way it reflects the facts and arguments that are
covered below, and how, since Till is
a chapter 13 case, those differ from the standard chapter 11 context; and
3) an analysis of Justice Thomas’ concurrence,
which supplied the fifth vote to overturn the 7th Circuit’s ruling
in favor of the secured creditor.
Then, I focus
on each of the passages in the plurality opinion that reference chapter 11
practice, and, in particular, look more closely than any prior commentator at the meaning of the term “efficient market” in footnote 14
to the plurality opinion.
I
identify a substantial amount of evidence that the loan market is sufficiently
“efficient” to satisfy even a strict
reading of the plurality opinion,
Then, I show
how lower courts have recurrently misunderstood the meaning of the term
“efficient market” in applying Till
and have also lost sight of the pre-Code precedent concerning secured creditor
cram-down.
I finish with a list of practical and strategic considerations for fashioning a case to overturn the use of Till in chapter 11 and a closing thought about the fairness of respecting market dynamics to resolve cramdown battles.
For those who don't have time to read all the posts, the first five posts focus on the Till decision itself, so readers who feel they are already familiar with it may want to skip those, although I encourage you to at least read the third post on the oral argument, which I think will bring to your attention things you do not know. The next five focus on the extension of Till to chapter 11; if you already understand the "efficient market hypothesis" in finance, you may not need to read the 8th post and if you are not in the mood for statistics about the credit markets, you may want to skip the 9th post. The 10th post is the one where I address directly the lower court errors.
The aim of these posts is to convince the reader of two things: first, even if you think that Till was correctly decided in a chapter 13 context (and I am not going to question its result as a chapter 13 policy, although I will occasionally drop a footnote here or there containing my thoughts on that subject), the “prime plus” method for pricing cramdown paper in chapter 13 was endorsed by the plurality solely as a pragmatic response to certain factors specific to chapter 13 that are not present in chapter 11 cram-downs. Second, subsequent lower court decisions applying Till in chapter 11 are (a) generally misunderstanding what “an efficient market” is and (b) disregarding pre-Code Supreme Court decisions which were intended to carry over into chapter 11.
The aim of these posts is to convince the reader of two things: first, even if you think that Till was correctly decided in a chapter 13 context (and I am not going to question its result as a chapter 13 policy, although I will occasionally drop a footnote here or there containing my thoughts on that subject), the “prime plus” method for pricing cramdown paper in chapter 13 was endorsed by the plurality solely as a pragmatic response to certain factors specific to chapter 13 that are not present in chapter 11 cram-downs. Second, subsequent lower court decisions applying Till in chapter 11 are (a) generally misunderstanding what “an efficient market” is and (b) disregarding pre-Code Supreme Court decisions which were intended to carry over into chapter 11.
Factual Background
Except as otherwise acknowledged, all factual recitations in this post come
from the Supreme Court opinion, the parties’ briefs in the Supreme Court, the
transcript of argument before the Court, and the 7th Circuit
opinion.
I’ll start with a short narrative of the Tills’
bankruptcy. In 1998, Instant Auto
Finance, a subprime auto lender, financed Indiana residents Lee and Amy Till’s
purchase of a used 1991 Chevrolet S-10 pickup truck at a 21% annual interest
rate, which, I learned in the course of my research, was the maximum rate
chargeable under Indiana’s usury law.
The loan was for $6,426 and their
bimonthly payments were to be $122. In
1999, by which time the Tills had reduced principal by about 25% but were in
default, the Tills filed for chapter 13 relief in bankruptcy court for the
Southern District of Indiana. The
parties stipulated to a $4,000 secured claim for the lender.[1]
The Tills’ plan proposed to repay the secured claim in
full over 17 months at a 9.5% interest
rate, at a time when the “prime” rate was around 8%. In the course of reading the transcript of
argument before the Supreme Court, I came across counsel for the Tills
informing the Court that the 1.5% premium was set by local rule, a fact not
disclosed in the Supreme Court opinions; that was quite a surprise, given that
the plurality would go on to declare that the “prime plus” approach provided
room for individualized risk assessment.
The lender voted to reject the proposed treatment,
objected to confirmation and, at the confirmation hearing, showed through two
fact witnesses that it “uniformly” charged 21% on loans of similar credit
quality and purpose, and further that such a rate was the prevailing industry
rate for car loans to credits like the Tills (none of which was surprising,
given 21% was the usury ceiling).
The Tills responded with expert testimony from an
IUPUI economics professor (who --
quoting from the Supreme Court opinion
-- “acknowledged that he had only limited familiarity with the subprime
auto lending market”) to the effect that a fair market price of capital and the
time value of money was captured by a market "prime rate" of 8%
interest, and that a 1.5% risk premium should be added to cover the risk that
petitioners would not make payments as required by the plan. By a remarkable coincidence, his testimony
just happened to dovetail with the rate established by local rule. The professor further asserted that the 9.5%
formula rate was “very
reasonable” given that Chapter 13 plans are “supposed to be financially
feasible”. Moreover,
the professor noted, respondent’s exposure was fairly limited because chapter
13 plans are performed “under the supervision of the court”. The chapter 13
trustee filed comments supporting the formula rate as, among other things,
“easily ascertainable, closely tied to the condition of the financial market, and independent of the
financial circumstances of any particular lender.”
The bankruptcy judge chose to allow the IUPUI professor’s
testimony as expert testimony, adopted its reasoning (I imagine the judge had
some involvement in crafting the local rule that the professor’s testimony said
was reasonable) and confirmed the plan in an unreported opinion in June 2000.
A brief aside: paying an academic expert to deliver expert
testimony is pretty unusual in chapter 13, especially where the amount in
controversy was less than $1,000.[2] So I looked further into the case to see if I
could figure out how that came to be, and saw that the UAW was representing the
Tills. The UAW apparently had a legal services plan for members, and one of the Tills was a member. In an earlier version of this post, I speculated that the UAW had invested in the expert because of the precedential nature of the issue, but Annette Rush, one of the Tills' counsel, informed me after reading the blog that hiring the expert was done just as a matter of trial strategy in the Tills' case specifically, and I thank her for enabling me to correct the recitation of facts.
The district court reversed, in November 2000, saying the
lender’s unrebutted evidence established that a subprime market existed and
that the established rate for the subprime lending market was 21%, which the
District Court considered the controlling inquiry under Koopmans v. Farm Credit Services Of Mid-America, 102 F.3d 874 (7th
Cir. 1996)(chapter 12)(“the creditor must get the market rate of interest, at
the time of the hypothetical foreclosure, for loans of equivalent duration and
risk”). The District Court stayed its order pending the debtors’ appeal to the
7th Circuit.
The 7th Circuit affirmed the reversal in August
2002 on different reasoning, 2-1. It
echoed the district court in stating that a secured creditor is due the same
rate it would “obtain in making a new loan in the same industry to a debtor who
is similarly situated, although not in bankruptcy” and “is entitled to the rate
of interest it could have obtained had it foreclosed and reinvested the
proceeds in loans of equivalent duration and risk”, since nothing less would
give the creditor the “indubitable equivalent” of its nonbankruptcy
entitlement.” But it went further than
the district court and announced that the pre-petition, non-default contract
rate was presumptive evidence of what
that rate was, adopting GMAC v.
Jones, 999 F.2d 63 (3d Cir. 1993).
The “old contract rate will yield a rate sufficiently reflective of the
value of the collateral at the time of the effectiveness of the plan to serve
as a presumptive rate.”
The dissenter thought that the debtors’ interest rate
should be whatever it would cost the lender
to obtain an equal amount of money, i.e., the lender’s cost of funds, and no more. Further, the dissenter contended that the
lender had already been fully compensated for the risk of nonpayment in the
interest rate initially specified (even though 75% of that loan remained unpaid
and the creditor was being prohibited from exercising its contractual remedy
for default).[3]
The Seventh Circuit’s decision reinforced a conflict that
already existed among the circuits. In
addition to GMAC v. Jones, five other
Circuits had adopted variations on the “coerced loan” approach: Matter of Southern States Motor Inns, Inc.,
709 F.2d 647 (11th Cir. 1983), cert. den.,
465 U.S. 1022 (1984); In re Hardzog,
901 F.2d 858 (10th Cir. 1990); United
Carolina Bank v. Hall, 993 F.2d 1126 (4th Cir. 1993); In re Smithwick, 121 F.3d 211 (5th Cir. 1997), cert. den., 523 U.S. 1074 (1998); United States v. Arnold, 878 F.2d 925 (6th Cir. 1989).
In contrast, the Second, Eighth and Ninth Circuit Courts
of Appeals had adopted alternative “formula” methods for discounting payments
to present value, generally beginning with a relatively riskless rate, like US
Treasuries, and adding a risk premium but also generally affording the trial
judge discretion in computing the specific rate. See, e.g., In re Valenti, 105 F.3d 55 (2d Cir
1997) (which, much like the Till plurality, endorsed lower court decisions
using a prime plus formula).
So, after several previous denials of cert, the Supreme
Court chose Till as the vehicle to
resolve the circuit conflict.
[1] The lender also received a
$895 deficiency claim which was not satisfied in full, and is not relevant to
my chapter 11 focus, but is worth keeping in mind to the extent one wants to
think about whether the Tills’ plan was “fair and equitable” in a broader
sense, especially when advocates of greater debtor relief emphasize the 21%
pre-petition interest rate and the supposed profit reaped by the lender. The lender here was not paid in full on its
total claim. I further doubt they were
allowed any amount for their legal fees defending their claim.
[2] On a $4,000 amortizing note
over 17 months, the 11.5% difference in interest rates amounted to about $500
in additional payments.
[3] In my opinion, that analysis
reflected neither a sound legal analysis of a secured loan nor a basic grasp of
finance in a market economy. The fact that a risk has materialized has nothing
to do with whether the government can coercively re-expose the lender to a
renewal of that risk or a different one, or at what price it can take away the
lender's remedy for the risk materializing.
No comments:
Post a Comment