Footnote 14 in the Till plurality opinion has become the
jumping-off point for the use of the "prime-plus" formula in chapter
11, and in this post, I will analyze it in detail. To begin with, here is the footnote:
This
fact helps to explain why there is no readily apparent Chapter 13 cram down
market rate of interest. Because every cram down loan is imposed by a court
over the objection of the secured creditor, there is no free market of willing
cram down lenders. Interestingly, the same is not true in the Chapter 11
context, as numerous lenders advertise financing for Chapter 11 debtors in
possession. See, e.g., Balmoral Financial Corporation, http://www.balmoral.com/bdip.htm (all Internet materials as visited Mar. 4,
2004, and available in Clerk of Court’s case file) (advertising debtor in
possession lending); Debtor in Possession Financing: 1st National Assistance
Finance Association DIP Division, http://www.loanmallusa.com/dip.htm (offering to tailor a financing
program . . . to your business needs and . . . to work closely with your
bankruptcy counsel). Thus, when picking a cram down rate in a Chapter 11 case,
it might make sense to ask what rate an efficient market would produce. In the Chapter 13 context, by contrast, the
absence of any such market obligates courts to look to first principles and ask
only what rate will fairly compensate a creditor for its exposure.
The footnote is susceptible of two readings: The first is that given by many lower
courts, beginning with In re
American Homepatient, to first look at “what rate an efficient market
might produce” and then, if none is discovered, proceed with the “prime plus”
formula. But if you look closely at the
footnote, you will see it says nothing about the “prime plus” formula at
all. It does not say “it might make
sense first to ask what rate an
efficient market might produce, and then….” It just says, “it might make sense to look at
what rate an efficient market might produce”.
Unlike the American Homepatient
approach, I think the phrase “might make sense” was intended just to indicate
the chapter 11 issue was being left open for future analysis, and not to impose
an "efficient market" hurdle that had to be overleaped to get out of
the "prime plus" formula.
Also, notice how the footnote only contrasts chapters 11
and 13, rather than asserting resemblances between them: “the same is not true in the Chapter 11 context … In
the Chapter 13 context, by contrast
….” (emphasis added). I find it hard to
discern any intention of the justices to signal in the footnote an endorsement
of applying their chapter 13 approach to chapter 11 cases, when the footnote
only works to distinguish them. If anything, footnote 14 is a caution not to apply the prime plus formula in
chapter 11s.
I don’t believe this footnote reflects an enormous amount
of thought about what should happen in chapter 11. Others before me have noted, for instance,
that the two citations of bankruptcy lending proposals are examples of DIP
lending – lending to a company that has just
entered chapter 11 – not exit
lending that would be more analogous to a cram-down note. The justices who subscribed to this opinion
do not appear to have recognized the incongruity, which I think undermines any
argument to treat this footnote as if it provided a definitive roadmap for
11’s. The terms of DIP lending are not
necessarily indicative of the terms that the borrower can wind up with once it exits chapter 11 successfully. Generally speaking, a DIP loan would be
stricter in terms of the ability to draw down, on the use of proceeds, would
have greater reporting and lender oversight, would likely prohibit all other
debt incurrence during its term, and finally would be of considerably shorter
duration than the terms of an exit credit facility. DIP loans have both the blessing and the
curse of being extended in a judicially supervised, fishbowl environment
whereas the debt of a company outside of bankruptcy is administered with no
such supervision or intrusion.
So I doubt the justices meant this footnote to suggest
that DIP lending terms were probative of cram-up criteria in chapter 11. Rather, I think it was simply an honest
attempt, albeit somewhat uninformed, by
the justices signing the plurality opinion to signal that they weren’t
taking a position on the applicability of the mechanical “prime-plus” formula
in chapter 11’s, because that formula was not compelled by the words of the
statute, but was more of a pragmatic approach to the chapter 13
environment. I think they were taking
pains to make clear that they were not making a rule that would affect chapter
11 practice and further recognizing the colloquy at oral argument concerning
the existence of a market for lending in chapter 11, and leaving the door open
to a future evaluation of the chapter 11 context specifically.
Notwithstanding these views, since many lower courts have
since chosen to accord much greater weight to the footnote than I believe it
deserves, for the balance of this post, I will take the orthodox approach to
interpreting Supreme Court opinions like sacred texts and assume that every
point made in the plurality opinion reflects their considered intent and move
on to trying to figure out what footnote 14 in the plurality opinion meant.
Clearly,
the focus of all endeavors to apply Till's
footnote 14 to chapter 11 cram ups rests on the term “efficient market”. Thus, the question becomes, I think, “what
did these 4 justices mean by an ‘efficient market’” Note that this query may be somewhat
different from asking “what is an ‘efficient market’?” The latter is a question on which at least
hundreds of thousands of pages, if not millions of pages, of academic and
think-tank study have been devoted, without necessarily arriving at a consensus
formulation that regularly applies in the real world. I am not going to address the broad question
in great detail for three reasons. First, although I have read several papers
on the subject, I don’t claim to have the necessary level of expertise to add
to the mountain of scholarly output on it.
Second, I assume the average reader of this post is not an economist but
a lawyer, restructuring professional or judge; I am doing a “deep dive” into Till, not into the efficient market
hypothesis. Last and most important, one of the overarching themes of this
"deep dive" into Till is
that the statements the plurality made were not plucked from the ether or
handed down from Mount Olympus, but tie back to specific points and concerns
found in the briefs and argument.
Footnote 14 is no different.
It can be traced back to a specific
colloquies with lender’s counsel during oral argument in which two things were
agreed: a) there is a market for lending
to businesses in chapter 11, and b) in the subprime auto loan market, interest
rates do not change as circumstances change because of the usury laws. As shown in the next section an efficient market is, at a minimum, one in
which prices respond to new information.
But, as the colloquy at argument confirmed, rates in the subprime auto
loan market failed to follow the sustained decline in interest rates generally,
due to usury caps; thus the subprime auto loan market appears to be
"inefficient" by definition. I
have already quoted the colloquy but it bears repeating here for emphasis,
ergo:
MR.
BRUNSTAD: Your Honor, the contract rate is the best evidence,
the
single best evidence of the market rate.
QUESTION:
Contract rate -- if there has to be a number that's wrong,
it
has to be that one. … The contract rate by definition was entered into
at
some significant period of time prior to the present, and the present,
by
chance in this instance, is 2 years later, and we know that interest rates
fell
at least 1 or 2 percent during that time.
MR. BRUNSTAD:
But not for subprime –
QUESTION: So --
what?
MR. BRUNSTAD: But
not for subprime loans.
QUESTION: That's
impossible. The prime rate --
MR. BRUNSTAD:
No, Your Honor. This is why.
QUESTION: If
that's so, then the risk went up.
MR. BRUNSTAD:
No, that's not correct, Your Honor, and this is why.
QUESTION: No. It
isn't?
MR. BRUNSTAD:
Because State law caps the maximum rate that can be paid.
QUESTION: Oh,
okay. … All right, because it's a usury problem.
MR. BRUNSTAD:
Correct.
And later, Mr. Brunstad told the Court, “what we're doing
is we're saying there is a stream of payments to be made here and we have to
figure out what it's worth. The best test for what it's worth would be what the
market says. Now, the problem is, is that in chapter 11 there is a market.
People do lend to chapter 11 debtors….”
To which a justice responded: “I understand. Tell me a question I don't
know the answer to.”
No comments:
Post a Comment