As the plurality, by definition, did not have a majority,
it was Justice Thomas’s concurrence that resulted in the 7th
Circuit’s decision being reversed.
However, as Justice Thomas’s views were more extreme than the
plurality’s, the latter, as the narrower basis for decision, came to be the
focus of subsequent interpretation (unlike, say Northern Pipeline v. Marathon,
where Rehnquist’s concurrence, containing the narrower ground, was considered
to be the position of the Court). Although I probably have a great deal more
respect for Justice Thomas’s jurisprudence than the average law school
graduate, because I find him to be both intellectually honest and
consistent, I regret that his
concurrence in Till is impossible to
defend. The concurrence takes the
frequently employed literalist approach to construing the statute, but
unfortunately has an extremely narrow interpretation of the relevant phrase:
“value, as of the effective date of the property to be distributed under the
plan”. Not only does his interpretation
ignore common sense and other tools of legislative interpretation, even within
literalist parameters, it ignores obvious alternative interpretations of that
phrase.
Simply put, the Thomas concurrence in Till states that the statute requires the “property” to be
distributed under the plan to be valued, and contrasts that with valuing the
debtor’s “promise” to distribute said property.
Justice Thomas then asserts, without any detailed explanation of how he
reaches his conclusion, this means that the only discounting needed is at the
risk-free rate, because otherwise, the bankruptcy court would be valuing the
“promise”. The risk-free rate, in his
mind, values the “property”, i.e.,
the cash that will be received in the future.
I find Justice Thomas’s logic far less compelling than the
blunt certainty with which it is laid out.
It may be correct to observe that the other justices are valuing the
debtor’s “promise to deliver property under the plan”; but Justice Thomas fails to recognize that he
too is valuing a promise. He is not valuing “the property to be distributed
under the plan” because no one at plan confirmation knows exactly how much
actually will be distributed. What
Justice Thomas is valuing is “the property promised to be delivered under the
plan”. He is just valuing the promise at
100% probability of performance whereas the others are assigning some lower
prospect. I see nothing in the Code to suggest that only the most extreme
standard was intended by Congress.
Even within the literalist framework, I can just as easily
conclude that the directive to the bankruptcy court to value what is “to be
distributed” calls for the bankruptcy court to take into account, not merely
what the plan says on paper is going to be distributed, but also what real
world outcomes can be anticipated as of “the effective date of the plan”, one
of which is not making the full distribution on time, and then to pack all of
that into a valuation that is fair and equitable. The statute does not say “promise”, true[1], but it also does not say
“property that is supposed to be distributed under the plan” either; it just
refers what is “to be distributed”.
Even more obviously, it seems improbable that a broad, litigable term
like “value” would be used without further specification if Congress intended
only a single, easily specified kind of discount rate was applicable.
Stepping outside the literalist framework, and looking at
the statute taken as a whole, I think a risk-aware valuation fits nicely with
the feasibility finding needed for a confirmed plan. Since a feasibility finding requires merely
preponderance of the evidence, a positive finding necessarily eliminates the
risk of default, as a legal obstacle, even where there is evidence in the
record of that risk. A risk-aware
valuation complements the feasibility analysis in a fair and equitable manner
by enabling the court to make room for both legitimately possible scenarios, as
opposed to being forced into an all-or-nothing choice between finding the plan
feasible and risk-free or denying confirmation altogether. Again, one has to ask whether it is plausible
to interpret Congress (a) to have intended that a feasibility finding by
preponderance of the evidence triggered a risk-free valuation of the plan
payouts, and no other rate was possible, while (b) using broad and litigable
language to establish such a specific and narrow path for judges to follow.
Justice Thomas’s interpretation also leads to nonsensical
outcomes in the real world that Congress cannot have intended. If no debtor under a confirmed plan can be
compelled to pay no more than a risk-free rate, then all debtors wind up paying
less than the most creditworthy citizens, the most creditworthy businesses and
pretty much all state and local governments.
Even less than members of Congress and justices on the Supreme Court
probably pay on their mortgages!
[1] A plausible, and different, explanation of why the
statute does not say “promise” is simply that the obligation of a debtor under
a confirmed plan is not a contractual promise but more in the nature of a court
judgment. Does that mean the federal judgment rate should be used? Again, I would
say, no – when Congress has wanted to specify its use, it has done so. The word “value” should be read to be what it is,
a very broad term that meant for judges to do case-specific valuations.
No comments:
Post a Comment